首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   59篇
  免费   3篇
财政金融   4篇
工业经济   2篇
计划管理   13篇
经济学   19篇
旅游经济   5篇
贸易经济   10篇
农业经济   1篇
经济概况   8篇
  2023年   1篇
  2022年   1篇
  2021年   1篇
  2020年   4篇
  2019年   1篇
  2018年   4篇
  2017年   5篇
  2016年   2篇
  2014年   2篇
  2013年   11篇
  2012年   3篇
  2011年   2篇
  2010年   1篇
  2009年   4篇
  2008年   5篇
  2007年   1篇
  2006年   1篇
  2005年   4篇
  2004年   1篇
  2003年   3篇
  1997年   1篇
  1994年   2篇
  1993年   1篇
  1991年   1篇
排序方式: 共有62条查询结果,搜索用时 187 毫秒
1.
We propose a new bivariate distribution following a GLM form i.e., natural exponential family given the constantly correlated covariance matrix. The proposed distribution can represent an independent bivariate gamma distribution as a special case. In order to derive the distribution we utilize an integrating factor method to satisfy the integrability condition of the quasi-score function. The derived distribution becomes a mixture of discrete and absolute continuous distributions. The proposal of our new bivariate distribution will make it possible to develop some bivariate generalized linear models. Further the discrete correlated bivariate distribution will also arise from an independent bivariate Poisson mass function by compounding our proposed distribution (Iwasaki and Tsubaki, 2002).Received March 2003  相似文献   
2.
We examine the impact of heterogeneous discounting on collusion in dynamic Bertrand competition. We show exactly when collusion can be sustained and how collusion would be organized efficiently with heterogeneous discounting. First, we show that collusion is possible if and only if the average discount factor exceeds a certain threshold, with or without capacity constraints. Next, we identify a dynamic pattern of market share that characterizes efficient collusion and obtain the unique long‐run prediction despite the presence of multiple equilibria. In the long run, the most patient firm and the most impatient firm tend to dominate the market.  相似文献   
3.
Meta-analysis has become the conventional approach to synthesizing the results of empirical economics research. To further improve the transparency and replicability of the reported results and to raise the quality of meta-analyses, the Meta-Analysis of Economics Research Network has updated the reporting guidelines that were published by this Journal in 2013. Future meta-analyses in economics will be expected to follow these updated guidelines or give valid reasons why a meta-analysis should deviate from them.  相似文献   
4.
The relationship between advertising and price is important because the welfare effect of advertising depends upon the price effect of advertising. We attempt to provide a better understanding of the theoretical relationship between advertising and price. We establish theoretical conditions sufficient for advertising to raise prices. This will occur, for example, when firms play a supermodular game – a structure that considers the type of advertising (i.e., persuasive, image creating, or informative) and the effect that advertising has on a firm’s demand and costs. We also compare results from two simple duopoly models, one with horizontal and the other with vertical differentiation, and find that only the model with horizontal differentiation is supermodular for the forms of advertising that are thought to raise price (e.g., persuasive advertising). In consideration of these theoretical issues, we then develop an empirical model to determine whether advertising raises prices in the US brewing and cigarette industries.  相似文献   
5.
This article examines relationships between stress, health, and participation in physically active leisure using data collected as part of the 1985 and 1990 U.S. National Health Interview Surveys (NHIS). In particular, the article analyzes: (a) the effects of life‐cycle progression (controlled for gender) on subjectively perceived stress and self‐reported health; (b) the role of physically active leisure in enhancing health or buffering adverse health outcomes of stress; and (c) the effects of selected social‐economic factors, such as education and income, on the relationships between life‐cycle, stress, health, and physically active leisure. According to our analyses: (1) stress is unevenly distributed across the life span; (2) stress‐reducing effects of physically active leisure are present among retired older people more so than in the middle‐aged life‐cycle groups; and (3) direct health‐enhancing effects of participation in physically active leisure are more evident than the buffering effects of leisure on stress‐health relationships. A critical discussion of methodological and substantive issues facing researchers interested in the relationships between leisure, stress, and health is provided.  相似文献   
6.
Abstract: This note discusses the factors behind the rapid economic development of Japan this century. Japan's experience as a latecomer in industrialisation has attracted considerable interest in both developed and developing countries, especially after the recent dynamic waves of industrial development in East and South East Asia. While Japan initially adopted a strategy of borrowing knowledge from the backlog of that accumulated among industrialised predecessors, it did not remain an imitator for long, but made a variety of institutional and organisational innovative changes to the original capitalist model. In this note, we argue that one of the most critical innovations has been the creation of enterprise networking which is a system of inter-firm linkages through which market transactions are internalised within a web of enterprises based on division of production processes. We also suggest that these enterprise networks are not, as is sometimes argued, unique to Japanese culture, but that they should be an indispensable part of institutional capacity building in any country. Many developing countries could, therefore, benefit from organising their small formal and informal sector firms into networks of production activities. Résumé: Dans cet article, l'auteur analyse les facteurs sous-jacents à la rapide expansion économique que le Japon a connue au cours de ce sièecle. L'expérience du Japon, tard-venu à l'industrialisation, a suscité un intérèt considerable tant dans les pays développés que dans les pays en développement, notamment aprés les récentes et puissantes vagues de développement industriel en Asie de l'est et du sud-est. Certes, la stratégie initialement adoptée par le Japon a consistéà“emprunter” la somme de connaissances accumulée par ses devanciers dans le processus d'industrialisation, mais il n'a pas conservé longtemps le statut d'imitateur, apportant au contraire diverses innovations institutionnelles et organisationnelles au modéle capitaliste d'origine. L'auteur fait valoir que l'une des innovations les plus fondamentales a été la création des réseaux d'entreprises, système de liaisons permettant d'internaliser les transactions de marché‘ au sein d'un réseau d'entreprises sur la base d'une division des processus de production. Par cette analyse, l'auteur fait valoir que ces réseaux d'entreprises ne dénotent pas, comme on le prétend parfois, une caractéristique particuliére de la culture japonaise, mais qu'ils devraient constituer une composante indispensable du processus de renforcement des capacités institutionnelles dans tous les pays. Par conséquent, de nombreux pays en développement pourraient, avec profit, organiser les petites entreprises de leur secteur structuré et de leur secteur informel en des réseaux d'activités de production.  相似文献   
7.
Japan's recent trade policy is sometimes characterised as ‘aggressive legalism’ in the sense that it aggressively utilises the multilateral trade rules embodied in the Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organisation in dealing with disputes with its trade partners. This policy may appear to be a marked departure from Japan's past practice of favouring bilateral, non‐legal settlement of trade disputes. Upon closer examination, however, while Japan has been moderately active in using the WTO dispute settlement process for resolving its trade disputes, it behaves more like a country that resorts to surgical strikes on selected targets (usually the United States) under a powerful cover of the European Community. Compared to Japan, Korea's attitude in the WTO is more aggressive. While the Japanese Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry (METI) is not content with the status quo and is seeking to expand its aggressiveness in the WTO dispute settlement mechanism, it faces an uphill battle. One of the difficulties facing trade officials in Japan may be the lack of a national system for lodging WTO complaints, open to any citizens or firms, like Section 301 of the US Trade Act of 1974 or the European Trade Barriers Regulation. Nonetheless, in the historical context, Japan is far more aggressive than in the past in utilising the rules of the GATT/WTO to advance its national interests. It will never revert to the infamous practice of bilateralism and grey area measures.  相似文献   
8.
This paper examines the determinants of corruption in transition economies. We found that the progress of structural reform, comprising marketization, rule of law, and democratization had a crucial impact on the extent of corruption control in former socialist countries.  相似文献   
9.
This study analyzes marginal social and private returns of R&D investment through the impact of international spillovers of R&D stocks. We compare the marginal social with marginal private returns using data of 27 OECD and EU countries from 1995 to 2008. We consider two channels of R&D spillovers: embodied in trade flows and disembodied by bilateral technological proximity. We find that marginal social returns on R&D are much larger than the marginal private returns for R&D‐intensive countries, in the embodied spillover channel. We also find that the embodied spillover channel through import flows is more important than the disembodied channel.  相似文献   
10.
Using a unique dataset of 730 joint-stock companies, we studied the determinants of corporate board composition in Russia. Despite the widespread image of insider control in the 1990s, a large number of Russian companies now actively appoint outsider directors to monitor top management. The findings reported in this paper strongly suggest that the theories and empirical methods of financial and organizational economics help to pinpoint the factors affecting the extent of outsider directorship. We also found that, among potential determinants, bargaining variables have considerable explanatory power. Furthermore, our empirical evidence demonstrated that Russia's legal system and its peculiarities as a transition economy also exert a certain degree of influence on board composition.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号